Coulson, Andrew J. (1999). Market Education: The Unknown
History. New
Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
470 + x pp.
$54.95 (cloth) ISBN 1-56000-408-8
$24.95 (Paper) ISBN 0-7658-0496-4
Reviewed by Allison Halpern
University of Wisconsin-Madison
In Market Education, Andrew J. Coulson applies an historical
perspective
to argue that the current public system of education is inherently flawed
and should be
replaced by a privatized educational market. As a former employee for the
Microsoft
Corporation, Coulson brings to this topic an "outsider's" view;
perhaps this
association with such an immensely financially successful company partially
explains his
optimistic view of not only private schools, but also for-profit
schools.
Using selected anecdotes from world history, Coulson builds an argument
against the
efficacy of government-run schools. He describes the shortcomings of public
educational
systems in societies such as Sparta, Rome in the Common Era, Germany during the
Reformation, and England, France, and the United States in the 19th and
20th centuries.
These examples are meant to support his assertion that governmental systems
of education
are inferior to private systems such as those in ancient Athens, pre-Common
Era Rome, and
Japan's juku system of the present.
For example, Coulson juxtaposes the free-market elements of Athenian
education with the
state-controlled schools of Sparta. He attributes the success of the former
society's
educational system to its few government regulations and marketized
structure, in which
any man could teach whatever subject he desired. Instructors had to compete
for students
and thus keep their fees affordable while offering attractive curricula.
Spartan
education, on the other hand, was entirely state-directed; boys were
schooled away from
home in a strict learning environment. The curriculum focused on physical
activity in
order to prepare them for careers as warriors. Coulson ties the harsh
education of Sparta
and the low level of literacy among its citizens to high levels of government
intervention.
One of the strongest aspects of this book is in this application of history
to policy.
For too long, policy makers have ignored the lessons of history when
developing policies.
Coulson makes a strong contribution to the field of educational policy when
he argues that
by studying the past, we can make more informed decisions. History can
suggest what has
worked, what hasn't, and why. As noted by David Tyack and Larry Cuban,
"History
provides a whole storehouse of experiments on dead people" (Tyack
& Cuban, 1995,
p. 6). In Market Education, Coulson demonstrates the utility
of examining of
past events in order to help shed light on current policy decisions.
But while historical comparisons are undoubtedly instructive in educational
policy,
they must used in a subtle and complex manner. The differing contexts and
meanings need to
be explored carefully to enhance our understanding of the similarities and
differences
between the past and the present. Alongside his descriptions of each
society, Coulson
needs a more nuanced analysis of the particular governmental, social, and
educational
structures, and how these factors, separately and together, influenced the
success or
failure of their respective systems of education. The author pays only lip
service to the
successes of the public systems in his historical comparisons outside of
their ability to
indoctrinate young minds and bodies. The monolithic nature of his argument
leaves little
room for Coulson to expand his analysis beyond a simple "public equals
bad and
private equals good."
Coulson devotes a large portion of the book detailing the shortcomings of
public
education in the United States. There is little in this section that will
be unfamiliar to
most scholars of education, except perhaps his heavy reliance on
standardized tests,
including the SAT, to measure student achievement and school performance.
But unlike many
educational researchers who critique the practice of public education while
remaining
committed to the idea of it, Coulson simply condemns both the practice and
the idea of
public education.
Included in the censure of public schools is a prolonged discussion of
methods of
literacy instruction. Although Coulson does not seem to have a background
in literacy, he
easily dispenses with whole language instruction (or, as he and other
critics refer to it,
"look-say") as "pedagogical oblivion" (p.167). He too
easily navigates
the complicated waters of reading research, admitting that the goals of
whole language are
admirable, but claiming that there is no empirical evidence of its success.
He relies
heavily on the work of Jeanne Chall but ignores the thorough critique of
her work by Marie
Carbo. In fact, he is silent on the body of research demonstrating the
effectiveness of
whole language instruction. Whole language approaches, like phonics-based
methods, are not
without their flaws; in Reading Lessons, Gerald Coles ably
discusses the
complexities of the debates over literacy and some of the problems with
various forms of
literacy instruction, particularly the depoliticization of literacy
practices.
Coulson's critique of public education goes beyond curriculum and pedagogy;
he also
attacks public school teachers as "anti-academic" and schools of
education as
"intellectually bankrupt" (p, 140, 144). While "not all
government school
teachers are low achievers with no interest in academics," it seems
clear that in his
opinion those teachers are the exception, not the norm (p. 141). With such
condescending
attitudes toward teachers, it is no wonder so many teachers complain of low
respect and
status in their field, a complaint that has led many to withdraw from the
education
profession.
Once Coulson has finished his condemnation of public education, he turns
his attention
to the solution, market education. Perhaps the strongest aspect of the
book, the section
on privatized alternatives explores a variety of options, including charter
schools,
voucher programs, tuition tax credits, private administration of public
schools, and a
national curriculum. Each one is analyzed according to the five
characteristics he
believes are most closely linked with a successful educational system:
parental choice,
parental responsibility for education, freedom for schools to operate as
they wish,
competition among schools, and a profit motive for these competing schools. Not
surprisingly, all of these factors are aspects of a free-enterprise-based
system of
education. Coulson's conclusion, then, is that the most effective
educational system is
that which most closely resembles free enterprise: for-profit schools with
private
scholarships for low-income students.
While Coulson's case for privatized education may be convincing for readers
who have
not followed closely the debates over school choice, it is seriously
flawed. For example,
he dismisses John Witte's study of the Milwaukee voucher program as
"suspect"
because he disagrees with the composition of the control group. Instead, he
relies on the
study conducted by Jay Greene, Paul Peterson, and Jiangtao Du, which
concludes that the
voucher program is a success. However, this latter study, like the former,
is highly
controversial; most of its results are not statistically significant by
accepted social
science standards, although the authors conclude that the voucher students
learn more than
public school students. None of the shortcomings of this study are
discussed in the book,
even though they would contribute greatly to the readers' comprehension of
the issues.
Coulson also neglects important works in school choice research, most
notably Geoff
Whitty's comprehensive review of studies from the United States, England,
and New Zealand.
In this article, Whitty concludes that choice reforms "that trade on
the 'market
metaphor' are likely to increase rather than reduce inequalities in
education" (p.
6). This finding is supported by Trading in Futures: The Nature of
Choice in
Educational Markets in New Zealand, a longitudinal study of choice
in New Zealand
which demonstrates that the educational market deployed there exacerbated
inequality in
the schools. The omission of influential research by Whitty and Lauder et
al., as well as
of other prominent scholars such as Jeffrey Henig, Sharon Gewirtz, Kevin
Smith, and
Kenneth Meier, leaves the book incomplete.
The educational system that Coulson envisions is one with as little government
regulation as possible. All but the poorest families would pay for their
children's
education themselves; those that do not have the money to do so would
receive private
scholarships. Under this system, wealthy families could send their children
to the most
expensive schools, while middle-class families would have to make do with
whatever they
can afford, and low-income families must rely on the benevolence of private
organizations.
There would be no regulation to guard against discriminatory policies and
procedures.
Instead of a democratically elected body governing the educational system,
we would rely
on the market to provide a just system. Given the market's abysmal track
record with
regard to social justice, it is imperative that concerned citizens reject
this scheme, and
instead stand up for the idea of public education and work together to make
the practice
of it more effective for our children.
References
Carbo, M. (1988). Debunking the great phonics myth. Phi Delta
Kappan, 70,
226-240.
Coles, G. (1998). Reading lessons: The debate over
literacy. New York:
Hill and Wang.
Greene, J. P., Peterson, P. E., & Du, J. (1996). The effectiveness
of school choice
in Milwaukee: A secondary analysis of data from the program's evaluation.
Paper presented
at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association (San
Francisco, CA,
August 30, 1996); Harvard University Occasional Paper 96-3
(ERIC Document
Reproduction No. ED 401 597).
Kasten, W. C., & Clarke, B. K. (1989). Reading/writing
readiness for
preschool and kindergarten children: A whole language approach.
Sanibel, FL:
Educational Research and Development Council (ERIC Document Reproduction
No. ED 312 041).
Lauder, H., Hughes, D., Watson, S., Simiyu, S., & Waslander, S.
(1995). Trading
in futures: The nature of choice in educational markets in New
Zealand. Wellington,
NZ: Ministry of Education.
Manning, M., Manning, G., & Long, R. (1989). Effects of a
whole language and
a skill-oriented program on the literacy development of inner city primary
children.
Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Mid-South Educational Research
Association
(New Orleans, LA, November 8-10, 1989) (ERIC Reproduction Document No. ED
324 642).
Stahl, S. A., & Kuhn, M. R. (1995). Does whole language or
instruction matched to
learning styles help children learn to read? School Psychology
Review, 24,
393-404.
Tyack, D., & Cuban, L. (1995). Tinkering toward utopia: A
century of public
school reform. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Whitty, G. (1997). Creating quasi-markets in education. Review of
Research in
Education, 22, 3-47.
About the Reviewer
Allison Halpern
Allison Halpern is a Ph.D. candidate at the University of
Wisconsin-Madison. Her
dissertation examines the educational activities of a youth evangelical
organization in
the post-World War II era in the United States.
|
No comments:
Post a Comment